Just to add to Bookbox's comments above. The amount of rates to be paid were set by the rateable value of the property - a notional figure for the supposed annual rental value of the complete property. So if a property had a rateable value of £20pa
1, and the rate was 4d in the pound, the rates to be collected was 20 x 4 = 6 shillings 8d or 6s/8d. Liability for this sum initially fell on the property owner but if he was not resident at the property it was generally the responsibility of the occupier or tenant to pay the rate. The law was very vague
2 on the subject and led to many disputes having to be settled by the magistrates
3. Obviously if there were several tenants living in separate households within the property, each would be expected to pay his or her share in proportion to space they occupied (or more likely the rent they paid to the landlord/owner).
In addition to the Poor Rates, there could be rates for the Watch (before police forces were instituted), scavenger rates (for the nightsoil men etc), Highways rates and so on. In some parishes these were all amalgamated into a general rate, in others they were levied separately. Not all parishes levied all these rates. For instance a rural village would not levy scavenger rates and might not have any paved roads to maintain. Also, being isolated it probably had no need of a Watchman.
Although theoretically paying the poor rate in a parish could confer settlement rights on a person, the 1662 Settlement Act required that he was paying over £10 per year in rent for the property. In the early part of the nineteenth century such sums were beyond the average man's earnings, and even in 1840 the average wage of an agricultural worker was only around £25-30 per annum rising to about £40 by the end of the century
4. Given the large influx of people from the countryside into the towns in the latter part of the nineteenth century, it became increasingly difficult to rigidly apply the settlement rules.
1. This is not dissimilar to today's council tax system, although the tax banding is based on the theoretcial sale value of the property rather than the rental value.
2. See clause 40 of the
Poor Law Amendment Act of 1834 for example. That clause was dealing with the eligibility of owners or ratepayers to vote for the Poor Law Guardians, but reflects the dual nature of the liability for the payment of rates.
3. See this article on the
LondonLives website.
4. See Arthur Bowley
Wages in the United Kingdom in the Nineteenth Century 1900 Cambridge University Press.